vrijdag 15 maart 2013

Innovation and Kondratieff II

Innovation is the true key to a more prosperous world!
   

Kondratieff

In a longer time perspective, western world economy appears to show a sort of returning waves of prosperous economic upswings and deleterious economic down turns. This effect is discovered and described by amongst others Kondratieff [1]. He coupled the economic upswings to major innovation breakthroughs. During the upswing however, somehow the innovative power seems to diminish and only to return in its full potential in the bottom, the winter of the cycle, to start the following cycle.

In the figure below a schematic draft of the last four cycles is presented [5].
 


First K-wave

The first Kondratieff wave is indicated to be coupled to the rise in steam engines and cotton industry. Well if we plot the number of steam engines used in the USA in a graph with the Kondratieff waves according to the wave patern as suggested by I. Gordon [9], the following image is obtained:




Quite astonishing, the growth in number of steam engines in the USA reached its maximum around 1910, in the middle of the spring of the third Kondratieff wave. The first steam engine was installed around 1776, well before the first kondratieff wave ended. The true rapid growth of steam power emerged beyond 1870, when the second Kondratieff wave was already in its winter period. The extreme and sudden decline of the steam engine from about 1909 was due only to the development of superior alternatives such as the internal combustion engine and the electrical engine. This decline, was a virtual collaps of an entire industry. 

The collapse came, while the steam engine industry was still in its increasing growth phase and was sudden and severe. Would there have not been any better alternatives the steam engine may have reached saturation around at the earliest in the 1990ies, as is shown in the following image:   




In this figure an S-curve is fitted, with the inflexion point set on 1909, around the year the highest number of steam engines were counted in the USA. Most of these numbers are obtained from old sensus data and are far from being exact. The effects of change of industry are however thus severe, that the inaccuracy in the data is of subordinate nature. 

What is striking is that the time span of the fitted S-curve from start to saturation easily stretches over all the Kondratieff waves now known to us. 



Second K-wave

The second Kondratieff wave is indicated to be coupled to the rise of the railway and steel industry. If we plot the total railway mileage in the USA a graph with the Kondratieff waves, the following image emerges:








Although allegedly responsible for the second wave, the greatest expansion of the USA railroad network started around 1880 and occurred only in the winter of the second wave. Furthermore the development of the railroad mileage and the number of steam engines initially developed almost parallel. Like the steam engine, the development of the railroad was strongly impaired by better alternatives, being the internal combustion engine powered road and air transport.  






If an S-curve is fitted on the development of the total milage in the USA, with an inflexion point set at 1895 again the time scale of full the diffusion of the rail roads untill its assumed saturation took from approximately 1830 until aproximately 1950, provided the better alternatives would not have been developed . So the total time span of the diffusion of railroads in the USA is about 120 years, spanning at least two Kondratieff waves.  


Third K-wave

The third Kondratieff wave is indicated to be coupled to the rise in the electrical industry and chemistry. If we plot the USA electrical power generation in the Kondratieff wave pattern, the following image can be derived:






Electricity production appears to coincide more with the fourth wave than the third K-wave. Although the first electricity distribution took place in 1882, installed in a power station built by Edison, the biggest growth of electricity production took place in the 1940-70ies. So this technology is more likely to have generated if any the upswing of the fourth Kondratieff wave instead of the third.

If an S-curve is fitted on the electricity production data, the graph below can be generated. From this graph, it appears that electricity is not yet fully diffused throughout the USA. The inflexion point of the fitted S-curve is set to 1988. 







Here again the time span between the first production in 1882 and saturation, estimated to be around 2040, is about 168 years, easily spanning over three K-waves. Remarkably, from 2008 the electricity consumption appears to stabilise or even to shrink.  It appears that yet a better alternative is about to break through and radically change the game. One of the most likely alternatives is solar power [10].


Fourth K-wave

The fourth Kondratieff wave is indicated to be coupled to the upcoming of automobiles. If we plot the number of licenced motorvehicles in the USA in the Kondratieff waves, the following image emerses:




ALthough the very first cars were built in the USA around 1895, in the end of the winter of the second K-wave, the biggest growth of the car industry did coincide with the spring and summer of the fourth Kondratieff wave.  

If an S-curve is fitted on the development of the number of cars, the inflexion point appear to be around 1980. The diffusion of cars throughout the USA is beyond its maximum growth, a full saturation will be reached around 2050.  





Here again the time scale of the diffusion of the technology of internal combustion engine driven road transport only diffuses at a pace slower than the kondratieff waves, it appears to take about 155 years up to full saturation. 



Concluding, undeniably, there are certain upswings and downturns in economy. These are however not so strongly coupled to the upcoming and downturn of innovative technologies as is often believed. The rate of diffusion of most (past) innovative technologies is of a different time scale than that of the Kondratieff cycles. The diffusion of steam engines in the USA up to the full potential is about 133 years, spanning almost three Kondratieff waves, the diffusion of railroads from its introduction in the USA in 1830 to its maximum capacity in 1930 is still 100 years, spanning two Kondratieff waves. The diffusion of road vehicles is from introduction around 1895 until its maximum, which is assumed to be 2050 is 155 years, again almost spanning three Kondratieff waves. Finally, the diffusion of electrical energy is from its start in 1882 till its maximum, likely reached in 2040 a full 168 years. Also spanning at least three Kondratieff waves.

To my opinion, not the innovation itself is the trigger for any economic upswing or downturn, but the valuation of the innovation and with that, the amount of money spend on a certain innovations by investors. Since any innovation appears to follow an S-curve (as long as no better alternative technology shows up), the early projections  of investors are by nature too negative.  Once the inflexion point is passed, the projections of investors are by nature too positive.

A first very illustrative and recent example of this effect is shown by the investors valuation of Facebook during its IPO. At the time of the public offering, the development of the number of subscribers to Facebook was already past its inflexion point. Linear extrapollation thus showed a far too bright future, and indeed investors were heavily overpaying [11].






Another illustrative example is the heavily underestimated development of the installed photovoltaic cell power production capacity. This because this development at the moment is still several years ahead of its inflexion point. The following figure represents the actually installed PV peak power, together with an S-curve fit and the 2011 and 2012 projections of the IEA, the leading energy research institute:



Facebook investors and highly recognized institutes with seasoned professionals seem to use linear extrapolations to estimate future development of innovations. To my opinion it is this behavior that drives the vast upswings and downturns in economy, not the underlying innovative technology.


Final remarks: The data collected all originate form various USA data sources. It is astonishing how well and how early in time the United States began to collect and publish all kinds of statistical information. Furthermore the USA was through most of the last two centuries the biggest economy on the planet. So not only is the data available from astonishingly early on, it appears to be both accurate enough and numberwise representative enough to sufficiently reflect global economic upswings and downturns of technologies.  

The S-curve fitting of innovation diffusion originates from relative early work of P.F. Verhulst stemming from as early as 1839 when he was describing population growth [12].


literature and sources


donderdag 7 maart 2013

Innovation and kondratieff waves


Innovation is the true key to a more prosperous world. It is believed that global economic waves are virtually induced by innovations in a kind of cyclical motion.    

Kondratieff

In a longer time perspective, western world economy appears to show a sort of returning waves of prosperous economic upswings and deleterious economic down turns. This effect is discovered and described by amongst others Kondratieff [1]. He coupled the economic upswings to major innovation breakthroughs. During the upswing however, somehow the innovative power seems to diminish and only to return in its full potential in the bottom, the winter of the cycle, to start the following cycle.

In the figure below a schematic draft of the last four cycles is presented [5].

  




The Kondratieff wave appears to show four seasons: the spring, representing improvement, built up and construction; the summer: representing prosperity and consolidation; the autumn: representing a recession, the occurrence of a plateau or stabilisation phase and the winter representing a depression, a crisis, wherein severe liquidations occur.

Somehow it appears that we find ourselves in the winter of a Kondratieff cycle, which started according to most internet sources in 2000 with the burst of the internet bubble [1,2,3,4]. Some believe it may last until 2020, so some seven more years to come. Older articles predicted that the Kondratieff wave was to reach its winters end at around 2000. Others are more sceptical about the predictive power of the Kondratieff waves and its frequency. According to Rothbarth, the real business cycle is in no sense periodic, but is a continuing, wave-like motion that varies considerably in length and intensity.[7].

The question is, is this model of Kondratieff so sound? Well for the sake of fun, lets dig in some statistical history.


Alcohol consumption in the Netherlands



The first, very interesting and relative reliable historical statistical data over the timespan of most of the Kondratieff waves are figures on the per capita alcohol consumption in the Netherlands. The alcohol consumption is given by the following figure [8,9]:






Clearly a wave pattern can be distinguished. A first major dip in the consumption of alcohol can be seen around the year 1859, a second major dip in the per head consumption can be seen around approximately 1943. With some imagination, we can see three major peaks in the alcohol consumption, the first being around the year 1832, the second around the year 1890, the last, with more uncertainty since the peak, if any, is still in the making, around 1992. Here the peak and dip years are the ball park estimated mid points of the wave maxima and minima respectively.

From the deep and lasting dip around the 30ies and 40ies, it may be assumed that the alcohol consumption and the economy show a positive correlation. This means on average, with economic upswings, alcohol consumptie increases, with downturns the consumption decreases.

In the later Kondratieff models, for example as depicted below, the year 2000 appears to be the demarcation between autumn and winter. We appear to be somewhere half way wintertime and the true depression is only about to commence. This later Kondratieff model is constructed by I. Gordon of the longwave group, a Canadian financial research institution [12].



If we apply the later model to the alcohol consumption figures, the following combined image can be obtained. The datapoints in the blue field are taken as the exact seasonal turning points in the red wave model line:



Here only the last kondratieff wave seems to coincide with the Dutch alcohol consumption pretty well. With a little fantasy, the first wave somehow coincides somewhat with the consumption figures, though the second and third wave are not representing the historically collected statistical consumption figures.

Apparently, the predictive power of the kondratieff wave for alcohol consumption in the Netherlands is rather poor... 



(Un)employment in the Netherlands


Another very well documented figure is found in the unemployment statistics of the Netherlands. These figures are very likely to be directly coupled to the economic situation in the Netherlands. Since unemployment is supposedly inversely correlated to the economic upswing, the inverse of the unemployment is taken. This is the ratio between the total work force in the Netherlands and the number of unemployed people. This figure, a measurement for the employment varies between a number of about more than 120 and about less than 6 times as much people in the work force as the number of unemployed people. A high value of this indicator thus represents an economic high, whereas a low number represents an economic recession or even depression. These figures do show some wave like behaviour as well. If the Kondratieff low's and high's are inserted, the following combined figure can be obtained [11]:






Well, from this figure, it becomes clear that Kondratieff's model does not apply well to the Dutch (un)employment figures. It is likely, that in the Kondratieff spring and summer the employment should go up, in autumn and especially in winter employment would plummet. In the winter of the fourth wave (i.e. now), indeed employment is rapidly decreasing. For the rest, the Kondratieff  waves do not coincide well with the economic waves as represented by the employment figures.



Silver price in the Netherlands


Another figure to test the Kondratieff's theory is the -again very well documented- historical silver price development. In this figure, the silver price is expressed in guldens, a nowadays extinct currency, though over more than two centuries, the Euro represents only about eleven years. Thus, it makes more sense to recalculate the last eleven years to the gulden than to recalculate 200 years back in the history of the silver price to Euro. In the currency recalculation, a rate of exchange of 2,2 gulden per euro was used.

Since silver has actually been the material, our currency was made of until 1969 the long term development of the silver price was only due to debasement of the gulden, being a silver coin. Up to 1800 it contained 9,61 gram pure silver, from then until 1839 it contained 9,45 gram pure silver, from then until 1919 it contained 7,2 gram of silver, from then untill 1969 it contained only 4,68 gram of silver.  Hereafter, the silver price was decoupled from the gulden, being a mere nickel coin [14].





From the figure above, it can be concluded, that the silver price in the Netherlands does not coincide with the Kondratieff waves. Only the Kondratieff winter we are supposedly in at the moment, represents a strong increment in silver price.


Consequently, the three above statistically sound economic indicators from the Netherlands do not follow the Kondratieff waves at all. Is the Kondratieff theory wrong, well from these few statistical indicators, that conclusion appear to be too strong. The figures above do indicate however, that the Kondratieff model is not that sound as many do make believe....




[1] Essay A. Spits (2002),  http://libertarian.nl/wp/2002/09/de-kondratiev-cyclus/

[2] Essay A. Spits (2008) http://libertarian.nl/wp/2008/12/kondratiev-winter/

[3] Interview D. van den Brink, J. kooistra (06-01-2012)
      http://managementscope.nl/magazine/artikel/617-dolf-van-den-brink-kondratieff

[4] http://de.wikipedia.org/wiki/Kondratjew-Zyklus

[5] http://nl.wikipedia.org/wiki/Kondratieff-golf

[6] http://faculty.washington.edu/modelski/IPEKWAVE.html

[7] Article by M.N. Rothbart  http://www.lewrockwell.com/rothbard/rothbard44.html

[8] Tweehonderd jaar statistiek in tijdreeksen 1800–1999
      http://www.cbs.nl/NR/rdonlyres/7934A2DE-B87C-4CDF-8BC7-D34F02225620/0/200jaarstattijdreeksen.pdf

[9] Factsheet Alcoholconsumptie:
      http://stiva.nl/wp-content/uploads/downloads/2012/07/STIVA_factsheet-alcoholconsumptie_26jul121.pdf 

[10]  D. Lounsbury, Kondratiev Wave Theory Deflation and the Greater Depression http://www.deflationeconomy.com/kondratiev-wave.html

[11] Unemployment figures CBS:


[13] J. Luiten van Zanden e.a., The prices of the most important consumer goods, and indices of wages and the cost of living in the western part of the Netherlands, 1450-1800 http://www.iisg.nl/hpw/data.php#netherlands